Understanding the economics of the minimum wage: trade-offs abound

SJ CM Peter Ortiz shocked many local small business people last week when he suggested that if you're paying your workers minimum wage, "maybe you shouldn't be in business."  In addition to the rather chilling, anti-business nature of the comment--especially coming from a powerful City official--many saw Ortiz' analysis as jejune. Page One Economics explores the complex nature of how minimum wage law affects employment, poverty, and the overall business environment.

{Editor's note: San Jose CM Peter Ortiz offered the following to the local business community at the 3.19 City Council meeting regarding paying workers minimum wage: "if your business requires paying poverty wages {Ed. note: In context, Ortiz is referring to minimum wages}, then maybe you shouldn't be in business. And if your business requires you to provide minimum worker benefits, then maybe you shouldn't be in business. It doesn't impress me that someone has thirty or sixty employees if your employees have to work two jobs just to pay the rent."}

Since its inception, the federal minimum wage has been used as one way to help alleviate poverty and promote a sense of economic fairness. The federal minimum wage was first enacted in 1938 as part of the Fair Labor Standards Act and set minimum hourly wages at 25 cents per hour, but the law excluded large segments of the labor force. 

The current federal minimum wage is $7.25 per hour, which means a full-time minimum wage worker earns $15,800 per year. At this level of income, a three-person household that includes at least one child (for example, a couple with one child or a single parent with two children) falls below the poverty threshold (approximately $18,500).1 

The Economics of the Minimum Wage

Labor markets, like other markets, have a supply side (workers supply labor) and a demand side (employers demand labor), and their interactions result in an equilibrium price—in this case, the price paid per unit of labor is an equilibrium wage

The minimum wage acts as a price floor for low-skilled labor. When the government (federal or state) increases the legal minimum wage above the equilibrium wage that the market would determine, predictable outcomes occur: The higher wage  increases the quantity of workers willing to work at the higher wage, but the higher wage also decreases the quantity of workers that firms wish to employ. The result is a surplus of workers, where more workers seek employment than there are jobs available at the mandated minimum wage—and the workers who fail to find employment are unemployed.

To economists, a wage is a labor market outcome. As such, economists avoid making value judgments regarding the "fairness" of a wage. Rather, in assessing minimum wage policy, they measure the economic costs and benefits of the policy and estimate how effectively it achieves its intended goals. As with any policy discussion, there are two sides to this story, and economists are split on the issue. A 2013 poll of leading academic economists found the profession nearly evenly split; 34 percent agreed with the statement that "Raising the minimum wage to $9 per hour would make it noticeably harder for low-skill workers to find employment," while 32 percent disagreed (the rest were uncertain or had no opinion).

In many cases, economists who support a higher minimum wage acknowledge that the policy might reduce employment, but they argue that the employment effects are likely to be very small and the benefits to wage earners are certainly large. So, many workers would have higher wages, which would boost their family income, and a smaller group would be jobless, which would reduce their family income. In short, the benefits of the higher wage outweigh the costs in terms of lost jobs.

Economists who oppose such policies argue that increasing the minimum wage does significantly reduce low-skilled jobs. For example, a recent study by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) estimated that raising the minimum wage to $10.10 would reduce total employment by 500,000 workers. Economists also warn of unintended consequences of the policy that might disproportionately hurt those whom the policy was meant to help. For example, since the policy reduces the number of jobs available to low-skilled workers, it restricts access to entry-level positions that the youngest and least-skilled workers need to gain valuable skills and work experience. In addition, too often the working poor do not benefit from the higher wage; rather, the working poor bear a disproportionate share of the jobs lost.

Better Options?

As previously stated, advocates propose increasing the minimum wage to help alleviate poverty among the working poor. However, it would be a mistake to equate minimum wage workers with the working poor. The CBO report estimates raising the minimum wage to $10.10 would result in an additional $31 billion in earnings for low-wage workers. However, only 19 percent of the higher earnings would go to families below the poverty threshold. Stated differently, 81 percent of the higher earnings would benefit families who are not poor; in fact, 29 percent of the higher earnings would go to families earning over three times the poverty threshold. Teenagers likely make up a sizable part of this group. In fact, the Bureau of Labor Statistics estimates that 24 percent of minimum wage workers in 2012 were teens. 6 The CBO projections highlight the difficult trade-off presented by increasing the minimum wage: A $10.10 minimum wage could potentially reduce the number of people (currently 45 million) who live below the poverty threshold by 900,000, but in the process, total employment could potentially be reduced by 500,000—a severe consequence for those workers who might transition from low-wage employment to unemployment. Many argue there are more effective ways to help alleviate poverty. For example, food stamps and other welfare programs are specifically targeted to help low-income households.

Economists also favor the earned income tax credit, which provides an income subsidy (in the form of a tax credit) to low-income working families. The tax credit benefits are phased out slowly so that workers are not penalized as they earn more income. This policy has proven effective in raising the incomes of the working poor while minimizing the unintended consequences associated with some other anti-poverty programs.

Conclusion

Low-wage jobs provide a key opportunity for inexperienced workers to develop valuable skills and work experience, a crucial rung on the ladder of success. However, the income earned is not likely to be sufficient to support a household. While raising the wages of workers seems like it might be a good solution, the proposal makes the mistake of equating minimum wage workers with the working poor. Rather, if the objective is to reduce poverty, it seems that using a more-targeted approach, such as the earned income tax credit, might be the most effective way to accomplish the task.

Read the whole thing here.

Related:

Follow Opportunity Now on Twitter @svopportunity

Opp Now enthusiastically welcomes smart, thoughtful, fair-minded, well-written comments from our readers. But be advised: we have zero interest in posting rants, ad hominems, poorly-argued screeds, transparently partisan yack, or the hateful name-calling often seen on other local websites. So if you've got a great idea that will add to the conversation, please send it in. If you're trolling or shilling for a candidate or initiative, forget it.

Jax OliverComment